Tag Archives: housing market

Discrimination on online platforms: a call for regulation


Context

In the housing and rental market, anti-discrimination laws in the US gradually reduced discrimination through the legal system for the past two decades. However, academic scholars (Edelman, Luca & Svirsky, 2017) argue that the emergence of online platforms facilitate discrimination, as these laws do not reach smaller property owners using online platforms. Airbnb, the world largest online platform for short-term rental and housing, adopts a design choice that enables discrimination on its platform. Hosts decide whether or not to accept a guest after seeing the name and profile picture of the guest.

Methodology and experiment

In order to test whether Airbnb facilitated discrimination through its design choice, the authors (Edelman, Luca & Svirsky, 2017) conducted a field experiment across five different cities, including: Baltimore, Dallas, Los Angeles, St. Louis and Washing DC between 7 July 2015 and 30 July 2015 (see Figure 1). Originally, the experiment aimed to gather data from the top 20 cities in the US, but the experiment was halted due to Airbnb’s systems detected and blocked the automated tools used to gather the data.

Figure 1. Research scope.

The experiment gathered a wide range of information about hosts and their listings (see Figure 2). Information of hosts include but are not limited to profile image, gender, age, number of properties listed and previous guests that visited the host. Information on listings include price, number of rooms, cancellation policy, cleaning fee, rating and whether the room was shared or not to control for interaction between the guest and the host.

Figure 2. Data collection.

After gathering data, the experiment sent 6,400 messages with 20 Airbnb accounts. Hosts who offered multiple listings on the platform were contacted for one of their listings to prevent the host from receiving identical e-mails and to reduce the imposed burden. The accounts used to send messages are identical except for two variables: i) race and ii) gender. Race and gender were indirectly embedded in the profiles through the use of names based on Bertrand and Mullainathan (2004). Additionally, to alleviate confounds that would arise from using profile pictures, accounts did not include a profile picture. Finally, the experiment tracked the response over 30 days after the message was sent.

Results

The authors found that guests with distinctive White American sounding names were accepted ±50 of the time, while guests with African American sounding names were accepted at ±42 of the time. The ±8% gap persists across characteristics of the hosts and listings as control variables. More important, the results infer that the discrimination effect occurs in differences of a simple “Yes” or “No” response and not because of intermediate response and non-response. The authors further found that the discrimination effect disappears when hosts previously accepted African American guests. Control variables including homophily concerning race, age categories, price of the listing and demographics of the vicinity are however of no significant influence on the discrimination effect. Discrimination further cause financial consequences, as host incur costs when rejecting guests causes a unit to remain unrented.

Discussion: strengths and weaknesses

This paper provides clear evidence of the presence of discrimination in online platforms. The relevance of this paper is also strengthened by the way it emphasizes discrimination in the online channels, while in the past the focus was primarily on discrimination in offline channels. The results are consistent with other studies on discrimination in the online rental and housing market. Ge, Knittel, MacKenzie and Zoepf (2016) found a similar pattern of discrimination in peer transportation companies such as Uber and Lyft; African American passengers face longer waiting times and more frequent cancellations compared to their White-American counterparts.

The research also has a few flaws. First, the research is not able to detect the type of discrimination that occurs (e.g. statistical discrimination and taste-based discrimination) and whether discrimination is based on socioeconomic status or race that is associated with the name. Second, the paper suggests that the discrimination effect occurs when users of these platforms gain the choice to accept or to reject guests and passengers, which suggests that the problem lies in the platform’s design choice. The suggestions to alleviate discrimination by limiting design choice such as removing information of guests and passengers such as concealing names and profile photos or to eliminate the screening procedures by introducing instant book options as the only option, may harm the user experience for both (hosts and guests) sides. For hosts it is desirable if they can maintain control on who they allow to stay at their place, while for guests the platform is attractive if they can choose the place and host of their liking. When choosing to reduce discrimination by lowering the user experience for either party, online platforms run the risk of becoming less attractive than their competitors and jeopardizing their own competitiveness. Ultimately, discrimination will continue to occur on competing platforms that do not change their design in benefit of combatting discrimination and the non-discriminating company will lose its competitive edge and fail. Third, the inferences made by the paper are to a certain extent limited to the US. A recent study found that racial discrimination is more prominent in the US than in Europe (Pitner, 2018). The focus on metropolitan areas also questions whether the same effect will occur in rural areas. On the assumption that metropolitan areas are more globally connected and face higher exposure to other races, one can logically assume that metropolitan areas are more tolerant and discriminate less against other races.

Airbnb adjusted its non-discrimination policy in 2018. Hosts are no longer allowed to request a guest’s photo before accepting a booking agreement (Thinkprogress, 2018). Based on the research (Edelman, Luca and Svirsky, 2017), the adjustment will not help as hosts can still view names prior to the selection procedure. A potential solution is to increase the prevalence of reviews in the selection procedure. Cui, Li and Zhang (2016) found that encouraging credible peer-generated reviews mitigates the discrimination effect of guests with African American-sounding names on Airbnb. However, we argued that the action of one platform may not suffice as a solution to stop discrimination and call for more regulation on online platforms from authorities.

Airbnb adjusted its non-discrimination policy in 2018. Hosts are no longer allowed to request a guest’s photo before accepting a booking agreement (Thinkprogress, 2018). Based on the research (Edelman, Luca and Svirsky, 2017), the adjustment will not help as hosts can still view names prior to the selection procedure. A potential solution is to increase the prevalence of reviews in the selection procedure. Cui, Li and Zhang (2016) found that encouraging credible peer-generated reviews mitigates the discrimination effect of guests with African American-sounding names on Airbnb. However, we argued that the action of one platform may not suffice as a solution to stop discrimination and call for more regulation on online platforms from authorities.

Sources

Bertrand, M. & Mullainathan, S. (2004). “Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal? A Field Experiment on Labor Market Discrimination.” American Economic review 94 (4): 991–1013.

Cui, R., Li, J., & Zhang, D. (2016). Discrimination with incomplete information in the sharing economy: Evidence from field experiments on Airbnb.

Edelman, B., Luca, M., & Svirsky, D. (2017). Racial discrimination in the sharing economy: Evidence from a field experiment. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 9(2), 1-22.

Ge, Y., Knittel, C. R., MacKenzie, D., & Zoepf, S. (2016). Racial and gender discrimination in transportation network companies (No. w22776). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Pitner, B. H. (2018, May 17). Viewpoint: Why racism in US is worse than in Europe. Retrieved March 5, 2019, from https://www.bbc.com/news/world-us-canada-4415809

Thinkprogress. (2018). Airbnb announces booking policy change to head off outcry over persistent racial discrimination. Retrieved fromhttps://thinkprogress.org/airbnb-changes-photo-policy-combat-racial-discrimination-4f71c375553a/


Ideal Flatmate: how to avoid roomates from hell


 

Ideal Flatmate

“Imagine…after months of searching for the perfect apartment, you finally did it!!you found the perfect house, close to work, recently renovated and within the budget! It even has a roof terrace!!but oh wait…it also comes with a flat mate! who is sloppy… and forgets to pay the bills…and he ate your sandwich! your SANDWICH!!!”

raw (220×120)

It is this kind of situations that Ideal Flatmate aims to eliminate.

Ideal Flatmate is a UK startup which takes house hunting to another level. In similar housing platforms, users would search among all the available properties or rooms trying to pinpoint the most appropriate one. On the other hand, landlords and flat sharers would upload a listing of their property (along with rules and preferences), hoping to increase the chances of renting it. Indeed, renting an apartment or room became easier with these platforms. However, what they could not guarantee was the success of cohabitation. The launch of Ideal Flatmate might mitigate this tricky situation. The platform came to shake things up, by adding a little of “matchmaking” in the mix. Users are asked to complete a 20-question survey (devised by 2 Cambridge professor) with questions focused lifestyle, living habits and personality traits. Then though a dating style algorithm, Ideal Flatmate pairs users with compatible flat mates. The idea behind it is not completely novel. Some roommate matching startups already exist in the US; although, they are targeted to students only. The platform is the first to enter the UK market and for the time being it is available for London flat sharers and landlords.

How it works

flatmates

The perfect roommate is 5 steps way:

  1. Register
    • Users can either advertise their available room or search for one among the listings.
  2. Ideal Matching
    • Users fill in the on-site survey. It takes 20 questions for the personality matchmaking algorithm to find and suggest the most suitable potential flat mates.
  3. Get to know each other
    • Users can chat and discuss with their matches through the message board. They can also create groups to find people to fill larger properties.
  4. Meet up
    • Users are now ready to take that “relationship” further and arrange to meet face to face!
  5. Secure your place
    • Users can move in and start enjoying the shared living experience.

Efficiency Criteria

Users primarily save time. Finding the right place to leave is like searching for a needle in a haystack. That applies especially to the London rental market where supply is currently on the rise(savill.com,2017). Browsing through a dozen of listings and subsequently meeting with numerous applicants,is time consuming. The tailormade suggestions of the platform mitigate this issue. The invested effort is also low, the platform is easy to use and even the survey is simple and quick to fill in. Furthermore, users are relieved from the stress and discomfort of ending up with unsuitable flat mates. In general, the platform comes at a low cost for the majority of users since browsing properties and flat mates is free of charge. However, in order to contact potential flat mates, users have to pay a subscription (either £4.99 for a week or £8,99 for a month). The subscription fee is a little bit pricy, albeit is more economical than the fees of competitive platforms (e.g Rival Spareroom charges £10.99/week and £23.99/month for complete access to the listings).Last but not least, specifically for landlords, placing a listing is also cost free.

Letting agents apart from being advertised, they also enjoy a grace period, since they also pay no fee.

To this point, Ideal Flatmate has not reached its full potential when it comes to maximizing its pay offs. The only source of revenue comes from the users that opt for the full functionality subscription. The platform is also available only on the London market, so the pool of potential users(and subscriptions) is also limited. However, the platform is backed up by government seed funding,which has probably covered at least the development costs.

Value Co – Creation

  • Users co-create by providing all the necessary information to facilitate the house/flat mate hunting process. By completing the survey, both flat sharers and flat seekers, provide the data (property/personality/preference data) for the matchmaking algorithm to work. Provided that the algorithm is accurate in pairing the right people, the chances of finding the perfect property with the most suitable flat mate increase. On the other hand, it becomes possible for landlords and letting agents to pinpoint the appropriate tenants (and essentially avoid short term contracts or early terminated contracts).
  • Ideal Flatmate benefits either way. The company does not own any property. It is essentially the intermediary that facilitates the whole process, by connecting and matching landlords with tenants and flat seekers with flat mates. Moreover, an amount of revenue is guaranteed since they have a subscription model (the company will have an income even if users do not find what they wish for)

Future

Regarding the institutional environment the company adhere to EU regulation (privacy,cookies,age limit and use of personal data).Since the company does not own any property it also not liable for any damage that was not foreseeable or caused by other user(Terms and Conditions).Overall,even though the idea might not be entirely unique,it is quite promising since it could solve a long-standing problem.To reach its full potential the company ought to start charging a fee for landlords’ listings and letting agents’ advertisements (company owners have stated that they will soon begin to do so). Currently, the platform is limited to the London market although within the year it is likely to be launched across the UK. If it proves successful in accurately matching people and Londoners indeed embrace it, the platform could potentially expand to other European capitals facing the same problem…hello Rotterdam!!

References

https://www.idealflatmate.co.uk/p/how-it-works

http://www.savills.co.uk/research_articles/141563/213355-0

Ideal Flatmate wants to be a matchmaking platform for UK flatshares

http://www.cityam.com/249058/start-up-ideal-flatmate-find-you-perfect-match-using